Monday, December 23

What Tunisia Did Right

Google+ Pinterest LinkedIn Tumblr +

Foreign Policy Magazine

Strong legislatures are a key ingredient in successful democratic transitions — and Tunisia is showing the way.
BY M. STEVEN FISH, KATHERINE E. MICHEL

It’s been two years since Mohamed Bouazizi, a young vendor living in the Tunisian interior city of Sidi Bouzid, immolated himself following the confiscation of his produce and scale by the police. Since then, Tunisians have experienced a wave of withering disappointment. Their courageous uprising deposed President Zine al-Abidine Ben Ali and sparked a region-wide assault on tyranny. Yet for many Tunisians disenchantment has replaced hope. While the freely elected Constituent Assembly draws up a new constitution, citizens grapple with a crime wave induced in part by the escape or release of over 10,000 prisoners, including common criminals, during the revolt that toppled the dictatorship. Citizens’ distrust of police forces that abused protesters during the uprising, as well as an influx of refugees from war-torn Libya, has sparked the growth of local militias. Tourism falters while unemployment, strikes, and migration to Europe swell, raising the specter of a crippling brain drain.

Yet a fact of great weight remains: Tunisia has made remarkable progress toward democracy. To a greater extent than any other country, it has shaken the perception that Arabs are destined to suffer the tutelage of monarchs, militaries, or mullahs. Why is Tunisia leading the way? Institutions — and especially the constitutional order — are a big part of the story. Much press coverage has focused on whether Tunisia’s new constitution will contain a blasphemy clause. Of far greater import will be how the new fundamental law distributes power between the executive and the legislature. On this vital matter, Tunisia is getting it right. According to a recent empirical study we conducted, Tunisia’s decision to create a system with a strong parliament and a constrained president is a recipe for robust democracy. Other countries in the Arab world can learn from Tunisia’s example.

In Tunisia, the Arab Spring has already produced a revolution. Immediately following Ben Ali’s departure on January 14, 2011, an interim government filled with his appointees called for a snap presidential election, but sustained mass protests forced the creation of the Ben Achour Commission, which agreed on the procedures to produce an elected government based on the vote for a new legislative body. In October 2011, a new government came to power following the first free election in Tunisia’s post-independence history. The Ennahda party won a plurality of seats in the 217-member Constituent Assembly. It formed a coalition with the Congress for the Republic (CPR) and theDemocratic Forum for Labor and Liberties (Ettakatol). The assembly then set about its primary task, creating a new constitution. As of this writing, the document is scheduled for completion in the spring of 2013, setting the stage for parliamentary elections later in the year.

More from
DEMOCRACY LAB

Is Indonesia’s national unity falling apart?
Prosperity Isn’t Just a Matter of Wealth
The sad reality of Egypt’s vaunted military

Tunisia’s ace-in-the-hole for maintaining its exemplary progress is the formidable power vested in the legislature. The elections for the Constituent Assembly served as the basis for establishing the new government, and theConstituent Assembly itself is on course to create a parliamentary system. Assemblies, rather than executives, have commanded political power from the onset of Tunisia’s revolution and are likely to continue to do so.

Tunisians are uprooting dictatorship, not merely expelling the dictator. They are not only changing the rulers but also fixing the rules. Rather than replacing the old autocrat with a legitimately elected but still dominant president, Tunisians are tackling the problem of overweening executive power head-on. They are betting on good institutions rather than on a strong, wise ruler. Their farsighted choice will yield benefits for decades to come.

The advantages of a strong-legislature model are many. From the standpoint of advancing democratization, the most important is the check placed on executive power. In polities with dominant legislatures, the most powerful executive is typically the prime minister. While prime ministers can be highhanded, they are usually more constrained than are presidents or monarchs. Prime ministers in parliamentary systems ultimately serve at the pleasure of their colleagues in parliament. Prime ministersThey are less prone to democracy-endangering imperiousness than are executives who are not answerable to the legislature.

Over the past half-century, autonomous executives have been democracy’s most obstinate foe. Even many figures with reputations as democrats who captured presidencies in free elections have subsequently abused their power and dragged their countries back toward authoritarianism. Russia’s Boris Yeltsin, Peru’s Alberto Fujimori, Kyrgyzstan’s Askar Akayev, Zambia’sFrederick Chiluba, and Kenya’s Mwai Kibaki are examples.

In most developing countries, executives — and particularly presidents — enjoy a big advantage. Most agencies of state fall under their authority. Executives typically also shape the judiciary. The best hope for restraining the executive is a legislature that enjoys real clout.

In a recent study we investigated the effect of the power of the legislature vis-à-vis the executive on the fate of democratization around the world. We focus specifically on two questions: First, is the legislature free of executive appointees? When all legislators are elected, the legislature enjoys greater autonomy from the executive than when the executive appoints a portion (or all) of the legislature. Second, does the legislature alone make laws, or can the executive do so as well? If the executive can decree laws, the legislature must share its central function with the executive.

Drawing on a global survey of the powers of national legislatures, we coded countries in terms of whether their constitutions establish legislatures that are free of executive appointees and/or provide the legislature with a monopoly on legislating. We analyzed how these two provisions may affect countries’ level of democracy. To assess democracy, we used data issued by Freedom House, adopting their categorization of countries as “free,” “partly free,” and “not free.” We may label countries in the first category as democracies, those in the second as hybrid regimes, and those in the third as autocracies.

We ran statistical analyses to assess the effect of the two constitutional provisions of interest on which category of political regime countries landed in as of 2010, on the eve of the Arab Spring. Controlling for structural factors, we find that each of the constitutional provisions has a substantial effect. We then used the statistical models to calculate the predicted probabilities of each of the countries of the Middle East and North Africa falling into the free, partly free, or not free categories.

The results are remarkable. They show that two seemingly mundane constitutional provisions that have nothing to do with region, religion, oil, or economic development may help determine the prospects for democratization in the Arab world. While constitutions do not always accurately reflect political realities, they very often do depict — and shape — the real distribution of power.

Under Ben Ali, the president both appointed some parliamentarians and wielded decree powers. Our study shows that this model yields a miniscule prospect — a two percent chance, to be exact — of Tunisia being a “free” polity. Its likelihood of falling into the “not free” category exceeds 70 percent. Yet altering the constitution to ensure that the president can neither appoint any legislators nor make laws boosts the chances of being “free” to better than 33 percent and slashes the hazard of being “not free” to ten percent. Creating an all-elected legislature that will not have to share lawmaking power with the president transforms the picture. The working draft of Tunisia’s new constitution, as well as prevailing political preferences among Tunisia’s dominant political players, indicates strongly that Tunisia is on track to adopt precisely such a strong-parliament model.

Other countries in the region would benefit from following Tunisia. Empowering the legislature also shifts the prospects for overcoming autocracy from grim to good in Egypt. According to our statistical analyses, with an assembly that contains executive appointees and that lacks a monopoly on the authority to make laws (as under Hosni Mubarak), Egypt has a 90 percent chance of landing in the “not free” category. If the legislature is all elected orgains a monopoly on lawmaking, the danger of autocracy falls to between 60 and 70 percent. Under the scenario in which the legislature is both free of executive appointees and vested with a monopoly on lawmaking authority, the hazard of autocracy falls to about 30 percent.

Yet Egypt may miss its chance to forge a truly transformative constitutional order. Its current draft constitution permits the president to appoint one-quarter of the upper house of the legislature. It also leaves open the possibility that the president will be able to issue decrees, thereby robbing the legislature of a monopoly on lawmaking authority. Mohamed Morsi’s assumption of the presidency in open elections and his subsequent efforts to restrict the military’s political sway represent real strides forward. But if the presidency dominates politics — as current trends and the draft constitution indicate it may — Egypt’s chances of lasting democracy are slim, even under a president who was freely elected.

Egypt is currently in danger of replicating the strong-executive, weak-legislature model the prevailed during the Mubarak era. Yet its constitution is still being drafted and debated. Egypt still enjoys the opportunity to augment parliament’s powers and escape the snare of an unconstrained executive. Will Egypt follow the example of Tunisia — and, before it, Turkey — and embrace an order that includes a muscular parliament? Or will it follow Russia, which enjoyed a dramatic political opening in the early 1990s but then squandered its chance for durable democracy by adopting a constitution that permitted presidential arrogance?

Other countries in the Arab world face the same challenge. In Morocco, the legislature was made up exclusively of elected members even before the Arab Spring; the king appointed no legislators. This condition already abets political opening in Morocco. The danger of Morocco falling into the “not free” category is a bit below 40 percent, and Morocco has, in fact, long ranked as a “partly free” polity in the Freedom House survey. It has enjoyed greater political openness than did Ben Ali-era Tunisia, Mubarak-era Egypt and other regional neighbors. Yet the Moroccan sovereign enjoys decree powers. If he were stripped of them and the legislature vested with the sole authority to make laws, the probability of Morocco achieving “free” status would more than quadruple, rising from 8 to about 30 percent. Morocco has recently undertakenreforms that grant parliament a bit more power, but these measures have largely amounted to cosmetic adjustments. They have not forced the monarch to give up his right to issue decrees that have the force of law. It remains to be seen whether Morocco will make further constitutional changes that vest exclusive lawmaking authority in parliament.

Whether hard-won freedoms take root in the Arab world depends not only on the courage and tenacity that the masses have displayed in abundance over the past two years. It hinges also on the more routine business of constitution-writing. The rules that define the power of the legislature are of greatest significance. Creating vigorous representative assemblies, rather than indulging the temptation to seek salvation in dominant executives, is the key. It will help ensure that Mohamed Bouazizi and those whom he inspired fell not merely to interrupt dictatorships, but rather to end them.

Save big when you subscribe to FP.
Photo by FETHI BELAID/AFP/Getty Images

M. Steven Fish is a Professor of Political Science and Katherine E. Michel is a Ph.D. student in theDepartment of Political Science at the University of California, Berkeley.

0 comments

Welcome to Foreign Policy’s new commenting system! The good news is that it’s now easier than ever to comment and share your insights with friends. Here’s how it works: You can now sign in by creating a LiveFyre account (which will replace the ForeignPolicy.com accounts from now on), or using a Twitter or Facebook account, and carry on a conversation with your fellow commenters in the section below. You do not have to sign in using a social network if you choose to remain anonymous – simply use a LiveFyre account to continue commenting. For more information, click here.

.

Share.

About Author

Comments are closed.